Home Data-Driven Thinking Inventory Price Opacity Hurts Publishers

Inventory Price Opacity Hurts Publishers

SHARE:

jalal“Data-Driven Thinking” is written by members of the media community and contains fresh ideas on the digital revolution in media.

Today’s column is written by Jalal Nasir, CEO at Pixalate.

Life as a publisher used to be pretty straightforward. You simply sold your best inventory at the highest CPM your sales team could get, and whatever was left over was filled in with remnant ads. Aside from someone making sure to avoid channel conflict, nobody paid much attention to what we now call RTB.

Flash forward to today. RTB digital display advertising now accounts for 22% of all display ad spending. Last year, RTB grew at 76.5%, and by 2018, RTB is expected to account for one-third of all display ad spending, or $12 billion.*

jalalAnd yet, not all players in the RTB ad ecosystem benefit from this growth. Publishers have it worst of all because price opacity prevents them from knowing the true value of their inventory. It’s estimated that, on average, bid clear prices for exchange-traded display ads are about 25% below high bids. As a consequence, publishers set artificially low floor prices. They’re losing money and, one could argue, are caught in a downward spiral.

How could this be happening?

Second-Price Auction Mechanics

The majority of RTB inventory is transacted through exchanges that use second-price auctions. They work like this: Multiple buyers bid on an available impression. Bids are analyzed in real time by the exchange. The high bidder wins the auction. The winner pays a clear price equal to the second-highest bid, plus 1 cent.

Since the high bid is not the clear price, publishers don’t know the true value of their RTB inventory, and, by extension, don’t know how to price it. There is typically very little information made available to them by their supply partners. The price data they do get only includes the clear price for the ads, which does not represent the true value of the inventory. For example, if the high bid for an ad was $5 and the second-highest bid was $4, then the winning bidder only pays $4.01. This model may work well for other auction platforms, such as eBay, where consumers bid on unique or hard-to-find items. It, however, is not well suited to purchasing commodity items, where substitutes are readily available.

inline_2

Subscribe

AdExchanger Daily

Get our editors’ roundup delivered to your inbox every weekday.

What makes this problem worse is diminishing bid density. Many advertisers now work with demand-side platforms, which aggregate multiple buyers’ bids into a single bid. There may be hundreds, or thousands, of advertisers bidding on the same inventory, but in the exchange, they appear far fewer in number. Lower bid density drives down pricing because there’s less competition for the same inventory. Defenders of second-price auctions argue that, over time, market dynamics will correct these problems and ultimately provide the best price for publishers’ inventory. Unfortunately, the time horizon required for this correction to occur is well beyond any of our life spans.

Not a New Problem

Historically, other markets have dealt with similar price opacity. In some cases, technology has been developed that has brought a great deal of transparency. Until Zillow came along, for example, there was no easy way for consumers to understand property values in real time. Sellers had limited price data available to them. Only licensed real estate professionals, with access to MLS data, could assess property values. Similarly, Kelley Blue Book started out as an annual automobile pricing guide. While helpful, it was a blunt instrument compared to websites like kbb.com, which is today’s Kelley Blue Book, and TrueCar.

The introduction of transparency into these previously opaque markets has increased confidence among market participants and created more overall transaction velocity. The real estate and automotive sectors have experienced healthy growth over the last few years. And while both markets are still recovering from the economic turmoil that started in 2008, it’s difficult to imagine that transparency has not been a critical accelerator of growth.

This same type of transparency must be brought to the exchange-traded display media ecosystem. Once market participants have a complete and accurate picture of price data, they will undoubtedly be more efficient, profitable and able to allocate more inventory to RTB.

But it’s unlikely that the major exchanges will move away from second-price auctions. It’s also unlikely that DSPs will go away anytime soon. So in the meantime, publishers must change the way they behave. They must invest in people and technology that can help them make smarter pricing decisions, which will ultimately lead to higher revenue and better profitability.

Follow Jalal Nasir (@jalalnasir), Pixalate (@PixalateInc) and AdExchanger (@adexchanger)  on Twitter.

Must Read

Comic: What Else? (Google, Jedi Blue, Project Bernanke)

Project Cheat Sheet: A Rundown On All Of Google’s Secret Internal Projects, As Revealed By The DOJ

What do Hercule Poirot, Ben Bernanke, Star Wars and C.S. Lewis have in common? If you’re an ad tech nerd, you’ll know the answer immediately.

shopping cart

The Wonderful Brand Discusses Testing OOH And Online Snack Competition

Wonderful hadn’t done an out-of-home (OOH) marketing push in more than 15 years. That is, until a week ago, when it began a campaign across six major markets to promote its new no-shell pistachio packs.

Google filed a motion to exclude the testimony of any government witnesses who aren’t economists or antitrust experts during the upcoming ad tech antitrust trial starting on September 9.

Google Is Fighting To Keep Ad Tech Execs Off the Stand In Its Upcoming Antitrust Trial

Google doesn’t want AppNexus founder Brian O’Kelley – you know, the godfather of programmatic – to testify during its ad tech antitrust trial starting on September 9.

Privacy! Commerce! Connected TV! Read all about it. Subscribe to AdExchanger Newsletters

How HUMAN Uncovered A Scam Serving 2.5 Billion Ads Per Day To Piracy Sites

Publishers trafficking in pirated movies, TV shows and games sold programmatic ads alongside this stolen content, while using domain cloaking to obscure the “cashout sites” where the ads actually ran.

In 2019, Google moved to a first-price auction and also ceded its last look advantage in AdX, in part because it had to. Most exchanges had already moved to first price.

Thanks To The DOJ, We Now Know What Google Really Thought About Header Bidding

Starting last week and into this week, hundreds of court-filed documents have been unsealed in the lead-up to the Google ad tech antitrust trial – and it’s a bonanza.

Will Alternative TV Currencies Ever Be More Than A Nielsen Add-On?

Ever since Nielsen was dinged for undercounting TV viewers during the pandemic, its competitors have been fighting to convince buyers and sellers alike to adopt them as alternatives. And yet, some industry insiders argue that alt currencies weren’t ever meant to supplant Nielsen.