Home The Sell Sider Waterfalling: A New Hope

Waterfalling: A New Hope

SHARE:

aripaparosellsiderThe Sell Sider” is a column written for the sell side of the digital media community.

Today’s column is written by Ari Paparo, CEO at Beeswax.

Why does waterfalling or “daisy chaining” exchanges produce additional yield for publishers?

I received a lot of theories following my last dispatch, which examined this mysterious behavior of publishers trying to draw out additional yield. The most compelling explanation came from my friends at Datacratic, who explained that floor prices are to blame because they are used to cut price reductions in the second-price auction.

I want to spend a little more time diving into the root causes and implications, since ultimately I think we all want a market that is more transparent, efficient and fair. We must resist the dark side.

The Sell-Side Cheats The Second-Price Auction

Obi-wan: A second bid is worth more than any floor price

If we accept that floor-price manipulation is to blame for waterfalling, we must also ask what a floor price is actually supposed to represent. Buyers and sellers tend to have dramatically different definitions and perceptions of floor prices.

A buyer thinks of a floor price as the minimum price at which sellers are willing to sell an impression. Presumably if this floor isn’t reached, sellers will keep the impression for themselves.

But that’s not the way sellers think about floor prices. Sellers think of a floor price as the minimum amount they are willing to receive from a specific auction before the impression competes with other forms of liquidity, somewhat like the “ask” price in financial markets. See the difference?

Buyers think of the sellers like Leia resisting Jabba the Hutt’s grasp, maintaining some dignity and willing to let the impression remain unsold rather than sell below a specific price.

Subscribe

AdExchanger Daily

Get our editors’ roundup delivered to your inbox every weekday.

Sellers think of themselves like denizens of Mos Eisley’s cantina, making whatever deal they have to so they can survive in the universe’s most wretched hive of scum and villainy.

To a buyer, the auction has rules, and as long as you work with the good guys, you should get good results. To a seller, each auction is another attempt to gain some yield before Han shoots first.

Second-Price Mechanics

Yoda: Only one bid the auction has, pay what price the bidder will?

If an auction only has a single bidder, what price is actually paid when we’re supposedly in a second-price auction? In most exchanges, the second price is the floor price. This sounds reasonable at first because what else would you use? But it actually gives publishers a profoundly perverse incentive. By increasing floor prices, they effectively reduce the difference between bid and price paid, thereby capturing additional revenue.

As Datacratic pointed out, this is the primary reason that publishers waterfall. If publishers use a single exchange and increase floor prices, they will lose yield from buyers offering bids that are lower but still acceptable. But by using multiple exchanges, each with a different floor price, sellers can cover more of the demand curve, not to capture demand with lower bid prices but to lower the amount each bid is reduced along the demand curve.

aripaparochart

Obi-Wan: I felt a great disturbance in the auction, as if millions of impressions suddenly cried out in terror and had only a single bid.

This discussion relies on a key assumption that auctions frequently do not have multiple bids and get reduced to the floor price. How often does that actually happen?

Amihai Ulman recently made a similar argument: The market for individual impressions is actually quite illiquid, even while the overall marketplace is awash in liquidity. He references a 2013 study showing a 50% difference between bids and prices paid for auctions. The implication: Bid reductions, which are highly subject to arbitrary manipulation by publishers, have a huge impact on clearing prices.

Perverse Incentives, Soft Floors

Darth: You underestimate the power of soft floors.

Some genius at some point thought of a solution to this whole bid-reduction problem. The conversation probably went something like this:

Publisher: What if, instead of reducing bids by a lot, we reduced them by less?

Vendor: Well, that wouldn’t really be fair. It’s a manipulation of the auction.

Publisher: It’s really just a different floor price.

Vendor: Oh, OK. Let’s do it!

Thus was born the “soft floor,” a level at which bids get reduced even in the absence of a second bid. How does this fit into the economics of second-price auctions, which are designed to give buyers incentives to bid honestly and accurately? It doesn’t. It is simply a setting that publisher-side platforms offer to allow sellers to get more money when there’s only one bid.

But wait, why stop there? If an exchange or sell-side platform is paid primarily by the seller and is not subject to any kind of audit, regulation or standard for the proper execution of the auction, how do we know what’s going on here at all?

I have seen SSP contracts that set a specific auction deduction (say 10%), then add on an additional “RTB fee” that is unspecified and at the discretion of the vendor. Normally, no rational businessperson would sign a contract like that, but when you can’t determine how much money you’re making anyway, why sweat the calculation at all?

Trust The Algorithms

Supply-side platform: I love you.

Demand-side platform: I know.

The evidence accumulated thus far suggests a straightforward solution to our problem: We, as an industry, should move to a first-price auction. The argument is simple: Second-price auctions work best when you have bid density, but in RTB, most auctions only have a single bid. In that environment, there is enormous opportunity for shenanigans.

When I’ve pressure-tested this proposed solution with thoughtful members of the community, they’ve made the counter-argument that sophisticated buyers know this is all happening and the algorithms adjust automatically. Thus, if a publisher is “cheating” in some way to artificially increase the price paid, the buy-side system will see that placement as less desirable and will, over time, bid less. Thus, the bid reduction is irrelevant since both sides are gaming it all the time.

I don’t buy that. First, implicit this argument is the assumption that it’s OK to screw over less sophisticated bidders as long as the cutting-edge algorithms can adapt. Second, the auction mechanics create real externalities for the ecosystem, including latency, an increased likelihood of fraud and data leakage from daisy chaining, complexity and opacity. Third, it isn’t just the buyers that are getting screwed here – the second-price reduction is a murky, abuse-prone part of the system that may hurt publishers as well. Finally, the complexity in pricing makes both buyers and sellers less empowered to make smart business decisions about things like pricing and channel conflict.

Another related argument in favor of second-price auctions: They remain useful for audience buys and retargeting since those buyers are willing to pay far higher prices. This argument also holds little water since it translates to “the unsophisticated buyers don’t care that they’re being ripped off.”

Why, exactly, wouldn’t a bidder prefer clear guidelines for what they will pay over the convenience of just bidding high all the time?

Wait For The Sequel

We started with talking about waterfalls, and now I’m basically saying everything is wrong and we need to start over. I’m not sure the situation is really that dire.

It’s time to develop some guidelines for how auctions should be conducted, a task that belongs on the plate of the IAB’s Quality Assurance Group. The programmatic business developed organically on the model of search, but it’s now time to straighten out some of the mess.

Buyers should ask their supply partners about first-price auctions, how floors are set, and whether supply is being waterfalled.

Sellers, ask your exchange about switching to first-price auctions and don’t use soft floors. Ask your supply-side platforms about fees they take on the buy side and squeeze out the hidden stuff.

Use the Force!

Follow Ari Paparo (@aripap), Beeswax (@BeeswaxIO) and AdExchanger (@adexchanger) on Twitter.

Must Read

Intent IQ Has Patents For Ad Tech’s Most Basic Functions – And It’s Not Afraid To Use Them

An unusual dilemma has programmatic vendors and ad tech platforms worried about a flurry of potential patent infringement suits.

TikTok Video For Open Web Publishers? Outbrain Built It.

Outbrain is trying to shed its chumbox rep by bringing social media-style vertical video to mobile publishers on the open web.

Billups Launches Attention Measurement For Out-Of-Home

Billups, a managed services agency that specializes in OOH, is making its attention measurement solution and a related analytics dashboard available for general use.

Privacy! Commerce! Connected TV! Read all about it. Subscribe to AdExchanger Newsletters
US District Court for the Eastern District of Virginia, Alexandria

The Google Ad Tech Antitrust Case Is Over – And Here’s What’s Happening Next

Just three weeks after it began, the Google ad tech antitrust trial in Virginia is over. The court will now take a nearly two-month break before reconvening for closing arguments right before Thanksgiving.

Jounce Media's Chris Kane at Programmatic IO NY on Sept. 25, 2024.

The Bidstream Is A Duplicative, Chaotic Mess – But It Doesn’t Have To Be That Way

Publishers are initiating more and more auctions – but doesn’t mean DSPs are listening to more bids, according to Chris Kane.

Readers Are Flocking To Political News, Says WaPo – And Advertisers Are Missing Out

During certain periods this year, advertisers blocked more than 40% of The Washington Post’s inventory over brand safety concerns.